Observers and analysts have attributed the reasons for the 2001-2006 housing bubbleand its 2007-10 collapse in the United States to "everyone from home buyers to Wall Streetmortgage brokers to Alan Greenspan".[3] Other factors that are named include "Mortgage underwritersinvestment banksrating agencies, and investors",[4] "low mortgage interest rates, low short-term interest rates, relaxed standards for mortgage loans, and irrational exuberance"[5] Politicians in both the Democratic and Republicanpolitical parties have been cited for "pushing to keep derivatives unregulated" and "with rare exceptions" giving Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac "unwavering support".[6]

U.S. Median Price of Homes Sold

Government policies[edit]

Housing tax policy[edit]

In July 1978, Section 121 allowed for a $100,000 one-time exclusion in capital gains for sellers 55 years or older at the time of sale.[7] In 1981, the Section 121 exclusion was increased from $100,000 to $125,000.[7] The Tax Reform Act of 1986 eliminated the tax deduction for interest paid on credit cards. As mortgage interest remained deductible, this encouraged the use of home equity through refinancing, second mortgages, and home equity lines of credit (HELOC) by consumers.[8]

The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 repealed the Section 121 exclusion and section 1034 rollover rules, and replaced them with a $500,000 married/$250,000 single exclusion of capital gains on the sale of a home, available once every two years.[9] This made housing the only investment which escaped capital gains. These tax laws encouraged people to buy expensive, fully mortgaged homes, as well as invest in second homes and investment properties, as opposed to investing in stocks, bonds, or other assets.[10][11][12]

Deregulation[edit]

Historically, the financial sector was heavily regulated by the Glass-Steagall Act which separated commercial and investment banks. It also set strict limits on Banks' interest rates and loans.

Starting in the 1980s, considerable deregulation took place in banking. Banks were deregulated through:

This deregulation allowed many risky products to exist (such as Adjustable-rate mortgages) which contributed to the housing bubble and easy credit.[citation needed]

Several authors single out the banking deregulation by the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act as significant.[13] Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Krugman has called Senator Phil Gramm "the father of the financial crisis" due to his sponsorship of the act.[14] Nobel Prize-winning economist Joseph Stiglitz has also argued that GLB helped to create the crisis.[15] An article in The Nation has made the same argument.[16]

Economists Robert Ekelund and Mark Thornton have also criticized the Act as contributing to the crisis. They state that while "in a world regulated by a gold standard,100% reserve banking, and no FDIC deposit insurance" the Financial Services Modernization Act would have made "perfect sense" as a legitimate act of deregulation, but under the present fiat monetary system it "amounts to corporate welfare for financial institutions and a moral hazard that will make taxpayers pay dearly."[17] Critics have also noted defacto deregulation through a shift in mortgage securitization market share from more highly regulated Government Sponsored Enterprises to less regulated investment banks.[18]

However, many economists, analysts and politicians reject the criticisms of the GLB legislation. Brad DeLong, a former advisor to President Clinton and economist at the University of California, Berkeley and Tyler Cowen of George Mason University have both argued that the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act softened the impact of the crisis by allowing for mergers and acquisitions of collapsing banks as the crisis unfolded in late 2008.[3] "Alice M. Rivlin, who served as a deputy director of the Office of Management and Budget under Bill Clinton, said that GLB was a necessary piece of legislation because the separation of investment and commercial banking 'wasn't working very well.' Even Bill Clinton stated (in 2008): 'I don't see that signing that bill had anything to do with the current crisis'"[19]

Mandated loans[edit]

Republican Senator Marco Rubio has stated that the housing crisis was "created by reckless government policies.”[20][21] Republican appointee to the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission Peter J. Wallison and coauthor Edward Pinto believed that the housing bubble and crash was due to federal mandates to promote affordable housing. These were applied through the Community Reinvestment Act and "government sponsored entities" (GSE's) "Fannie Mae" (Federal National Mortgage Association) and "Freddie Mac" (Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation).[22] Journalist Daniel Indiviglio argues the two GSE's played a major role, while not denying the importance of Wall Street and others in the private sector in creating the collapse.[4]

The Housing and Community Development Act of 1992 established an affordable housing loan purchase mandate for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and that mandate was to be regulated by HUD. Initially, the 1992 legislation required that 30 percent or more of Fannie's and Freddie's loan purchases be related to affordable housing. However, HUD was given the power to set future requirements. In 1995 HUD mandated that 40 percent of Fannie and Freddie's loan purchases would have to support affordable housing. In 1996, HUD directed Freddie and Fannie to provide at least 42% of their mortgage financing to borrowers with income below the median in their area. This target was increased to 50% in 2000 and 52% in 2005. Under the Bush Administration HUD continued to pressure Fannie and Freddie to increase affordable housing purchases - to as high as 56 percent by the year 2008.[22] To satisfy these mandates, Fannie and Freddie eventually announced low-income and minority loan commitments totaling $5 trillion.[23]Critics argue that, to meet these commitments, Fannie and Freddie promoted a loosening of lending standards - industry-wide.[24]

Regarding the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA), Economist Stan Liebowitz wrote in the New York Post that a strengthening of the CRA in the 1990s encouraged a loosening of lending standards throughout the banking industry. He also charged the Federal Reserve with ignoring the negative impact of the CRA.[25] American Enterprise Institute Scholar Edward Pinto noted that, in 2008, Bank of America reported that its CRA portfolio, which constituted only 7 percent of its owned residential mortgages, was responsible for 29 percent of its losses.[26] A Cleveland Plain Dealer investigation found that "The City of Cleveland has aggravated its vexing foreclosure problems and has lost millions in tax dollars by helping people buy homes they could not afford." The newspaper added that these problem mortgages "typically came from local banks fulfilling federal requirements to lend money in poorer neighborhoods."[27][28]

Others argue that "pretty much all the evidence on the housing crisis shows" that Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, the (CRA) and their affordability goals were not a major reason for the bubble and crash.[18][20][29]

Law professor David Min argues that view (blaming GSE's and CRA) "is clearly contradicted by the facts", namely that

  • Parallel bubble-bust cycles occurred outside of the residential housing markets (for example, in commercial real estate and consumer credit).
  • Parallel financial crises struck other countries, which did not have analogous affordable housing policies
  • The U.S. government's market share of home mortgages was actually declining precipitously during the housing bubble of the 2000s.[30]

However, according to Peter J. Wallison, other developed countries with "large bubbles during the 1997-2007 period" had "far lower ... losses associated with mortgage delinquencies and defaults" because (according to Wallison), these countries' bubbles were not supported by a huge number of government mandated substandard loans - generally with low or no downpayments" as was the case in the US.[31]

Other analysis calls into question the validity of comparing the residential loan crisis to the commercial loan crisis. After researching the default of commercial loans during the financial crisis, Xudong An and Anthony B. Sanders reported (in December 2010): "We find limited evidence that substantial deterioration in CMBS [commercial mortgage-backed securities] loan underwriting occurred prior to the crisis."[32] Other analysts support the contention that the crisis in commercial real estate and related lending took place after the crisis in residential real estate. Business journalist Kimberly Amadeo reports: "The first signs of decline in residential real estate occurred in 2006. Three years later, commercial real estate started feeling the effects.[33] Denice A. Gierach, a real estate attorney and CPA, wrote:

...most of the commercial real estate loans were good loans destroyed by a really bad economy. In other words, the borrowers did not cause the loans to go bad, it was the economy.[34]

In their book on the financial crisis Business journalists Bethany McLean and Joe Nocera argue that the charges against Fannie and Freddie are "completely upside down; Fannie and Freddie raced to get into subprime mortgages because they feared being left behind by their nongovernment competitors."[35]

Most early estimates showed that the subprime mortgage boom and the subsequent crash were very much concentrated in the private market, not the public market of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.[20] According to an estimate made by the Federal Reserve in 2008, more than 84 percent of the subprime mortgages came from private lending institutions in 2006.[29] The share of subprime loans insured by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac also decreased as the bubble got bigger (from a high of insuring 48 percent to insuring 24 percent of all subprime loans in 2006).[29]

To make its estimate, the Federal Reserve did not directly analyze the characteristics of the loans (such as downpayment sizes); rather, it assumed that loans carrying interest rates 3% or more higher than normal rates were subprime and loans with lower interest rates were prime. Critics dispute the Federal Reserve's use of interest rates to distinguish prime from subprime loans. They say that subprime loan estimates based on use of the high-interest-rate proxy are distorted because government programs generally promote low-interest rate loans - even when the loans are to borrowers who are clearly subprime.[36]

According to Min, while Fannie and Freddie did buy high-risk mortgage-backed securities,

they did not buy enough of them to be blamed for the mortgage crisis. Highly respected analysts who have looked at these data in much greater detail than Wallison, Pinto, or myself, including the nonpartisan Government Accountability Office,[37]the Harvard Joint Center for Housing Studies,[38] the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission majority,[39] the Federal Housing Finance Agency,[40] and virtually all academics, including the University of North Carolina,[41] Glaeser et al. at Harvard,[42]and the St. Louis Federal Reserve,[43] have all rejected the Wallison/Pinto argument that federal affordable housing policies were responsible for the proliferation of actual high-risk mortgages over the past decade.[30]

Min's contention that Fannie and Freddie did not buy a significant amount of high-risk mortgage backed securities must be evaluated in light of subsequent SEC security fraud charges brought against executives of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in December 2011. Significantly, the SEC alleged (and still maintains) that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac reported as subprime and substandard less than 10 percent of their actual subprime and substandard loans.[44] In other words, the substandard loans held in the GSE portfolios may have been 10 times greater than originally reported. According to Peter Wallison of the American Enterprise Institute, that would make the SEC's estimate of GSE substandard loans about $2 trillion - significantly higher than Edward Pinto's estimate.[45][46]

The Federal Reserve also estimated that only six percent of higher-priced loans were extended by Community Reinvestment Act-covered lenders to lower-income borrowers or CRA neighborhoods.[20][47][48] (As it did with respect to GSE loans, the Federal Reserve assumed that all CRA loans were prime unless they carried interest rates 3% or more above the normal rate, an assumption disputed by others.)[36] In a 2008 speech, Federal Reserve Governor Randall Kroszner, argued that the CRA could not be responsible for thesubprime mortgage crisis, stating that

"first, only a small portion of subprime mortgage originations are related to the CRA. Second, CRA-related loans appear to perform comparably to other types of subprime loans. Taken together... we believe that the available evidence runs counter to the contention that the CRA contributed in any substantive way to the current mortgage crisis"

Others, such as Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Chairman Sheila Bair,[49] and Ellen Seidman of the New America Foundation[50]also argue that the CRA was not responsible for the crisis. The CRA also only affected one out of the top 25 subprime lenders.[29]According to several economists, Community Reinvestment Act loans outperformed other "subprime" mortgages, and GSE mortgages performed better than private label securitizations.[18][51]

Nonetheless, economists at the National Bureau of Economic Research concluded that banks undergoing CRA-related regulatory exams took additional mortgage lending risk. The authors of a study entitled "Did the Community Reinvestment Act Lead to Risky Lending?" compared "the lending behavior of banks undergoing CRA exams within a given census tract in a given month (the treatment group) to the behavior of banks operating in the same census tract-month that did not face these exams (the control group). This comparison clearly indicates that adherence to the CRA led to riskier lending by banks." They concluded: "The evidence shows that around CRA examinations, when incentives to conform to CRA standards are particularly high, banks not only increase lending rates but also appear to originate loans that are markedly riskier." Loan delinquency averaged 15% higher in the treatment group than the control group one year after mortgage origination.[52]

Historically low interest rates[edit]

According to some, such as John B. Taylor and Thomas M. Hoenig, "excessive risk-taking and the housing boom" were brought on by the Federal Reserve holding "interest rates too low for too long".[53][54]

In the wake of the dot-com crash and the subsequent 2001-2002 recession the Federal Reserve dramatically lowered interest rates to historically low levels, from about 6.5% to just 1%. This spurred easy credit for banks to make loans. By 2006 the rates had moved up to 5.25% which lowered the demand and increased the monthly payments for adjustable rate mortgages. The resulting foreclosures increased supply, dropping housing prices further. Former Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan admitted that the housing bubble was "fundamentally engendered by the decline in real long-term interest rates."[55]

Mortgages had been bundled together and sold on Wall Street to investors and other countries looking for a higher return than the 1% offered by Federal Reserve. The percentage of risky mortgages was increased while rating companies claimed they were all top-rated. Instead of the limited regions suffering the housing drop, it was felt around the world. The Congressmen who had pushed to create subprime loans[56][57] now cited Wall Street and their rating companies for misleading these investors.[58][59]

Historical chart of the effective federal interest rates, known as the Federal Funds Rate. From 2001 to 2006 interest rates were dramatically lowered (due to the Dot-com crash) but then increased from 2006 to 2007.

In the United States, mortgage rates are typically set in relation to 10-year treasury bondyields, which, in turn, are affected by Federal Funds rates. The Federal Reserve acknowledges the connection between lower interest rates, higher home values, and the increased liquidity the higher home values bring to the overall economy.[60] A Federal Reserve report reads:

Like other asset prices, house prices are influenced by interest rates, and in some countries, the housing market is a key channel of monetary policy transmission.[61]

For this reason, some have criticized then Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan for "engineering" the housing bubble,[62][63][64][65][66][67] saying, e.g., "It was the Federal Reserve-engineered decline in rates that inflated the housing bubble."[68] Between 2000 and 2003, the interest rate on 30-year fixed-rate mortgages fell 2.5 percentage points (from 8% to all-time historical low of about 5.5%). The interest rate on one-year adjustable rate mortgages (1/1 ARMs) fell 3 percentage points (from about 7% to about 4%). Richard Fisher, president of the Dallas Fed, said in 2006 that the Fed's low interest-rate policies unintentionally prompted speculation in the housing market, and that the subsequent "substantial correction [is] inflicting real costs to millions of homeowners."[69][70]

A drop in mortgage interest rates reduces the cost of borrowing and should logically result in an increase in prices in a market where most people borrow money to purchase a home (for instance, in the United States), so that average payments remain constant. If one assumes that the housing market is efficient, the expected change in housing prices (relative to interest rates) can be computed mathematically. The calculation in the sidebox shows that a 1 percentage point change in interest rates would theoretically affect home prices by about 10% (given 2005 rates on fixed-rate mortgages). This represents a 10-to-1 multiplier between percentage point changes in interest rates and percentage change in home prices. For interest-only mortgages (at 2005 rates), this yields about a 16% change in principal for a 1% change in interest rates at current rates. Therefore, the 2% drop in long-term interest rates can account for about a 10 × 2% = 20% rise in home prices if every buyer is using a fixed-rate mortgage (FRM), or about 16 × 3% ≈ 50% if every buyer is using an adjustable rate mortgage (ARM) whose interest rates dropped 3%.

Robert Shiller shows that the inflation adjusted U.S. home price increase has been about 45% during this period,[71] an increase in valuations that is approximately consistent with most buyers financing their purchases using ARMs. In areas of the United States believed to have a housing bubble, price increases have far exceeded the 50% that might be explained by the cost of borrowing using ARMs. For example, in San Diego area, average mortgage payments grew 50% between 2001 and 2004. When interest rates rise, a reasonable question is how much house prices will fall, and what effect this will have on those holding negative equity, as well as on theU.S. economy in general. The salient question is whether interest rates are a determining factor in specific markets where there is high sensitivity to housing affordability. (Thomas Sowell points out that these markets where there is high sensitivity to housing affordability are created by laws that restrict land use and thus its supply. In areas like Houston which has no zoning laws the Fed rate had no effect.)[72]

Return to higher rates[edit]

Between 2004 and 2006, the Fed raised interest rates 17 times, increasing them from 1% to 5.25%, before pausing.[73] The Fed paused raising interest rates because of the concern that an accelerating downturn in the housing market could undermine the overall economy, just as the crash of the dot-com bubble in 2000 contributed to the subsequent recession. However, New York University economistNouriel Roubini asserted that "The Fed should have tightened earlier to avoid a festering of the housing bubble early on."[74]

There was a great debate as to whether or not the Fed would lower rates in late 2007. The majority of economists expected the Fed to maintain the Fed funds rate at 5.25 percent through 2008;[75] however, on September 18, it lowered the rate to 4.75 percent.[76]

Differential relationship between interest rates and affordability.
An approximate formula can be obtained that provides the relationship between changes in interest rates and changes in home affordability. The computation proceeds by designating affordability (the monthly mortgage payment) constant, and differentiating the equation for monthly payments

with respect to the interest rate r, then solving for the change in Principal. Using the approximation  (K → ∞, and e = 2.718... is the base of the natural logarithm) for continuously compounded interest, this results in the approximate equation

(fixed-rate loans). For interest-only mortgages, the change in principal yielding the same monthly payment is

(interest-only loans). This calculation shows that a 1 percentage point change in interest rates would theoretically affect home prices by about 10% (given 2005 rates) on fixed-rate mortgages, and about 16% for interest-only mortgages. Robert Shiller does compare interest rates and overall U.S. home prices over the period 1890-2004 and concludes that interest rates do not explain historic trends for the country.[71]

Regions affected[edit]

Home price appreciation has been non-uniform to such an extent that some economists, including former Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan, argued[when?]that the United States was not experiencing a nationwide housing bubble per se, but a number of local bubbles.[77] However, in 2007 Greenspan admitted that there was in fact a bubble in the US housing market, and that "all the froth bubbles add up to an aggregate bubble."[78]

Despite greatly relaxed lending standards and low interest rates, many regions of the country saw very little growth during the "bubble period". Out of 20 largest metropolitan areas tracked by the S&P/Case-Shiller house price index, six (Dallas, Cleveland, Detroit, Denver, Atlanta, and Charlotte) saw less than 10% price growth in inflation-adjusted terms in 2001-2006.[79] During the same period, seven metropolitan areas (Tampa, Miami, San Diego, Los Angeles, Las Vegas, Phoenix, and Washington DC) appreciated by more than 80%.

Somewhat paradoxically, as the housing bubble deflates[80] some metropolitan areas (such as Denver and Atlanta) have been experiencing high foreclosure rates, even though they did not see much house appreciation in the first place and therefore did not appear to be contributing to the national bubble. This was also true of some cities in theRust Belt such as Detroit[81] and Cleveland,[82] where weak local economies had produced little house price appreciation early in the decade but still saw declining values and increased foreclosures in 2007. As of January 2009 California, Michigan, Ohio and Florida were the states with the highest foreclosure rates.

'Mania' for home ownership[edit]

Americans' love of their homes is widely known and acknowledged;[83]however, many believe that enthusiasm for home ownership is currently high even by American standards, calling the real estate market "frothy",[84]"speculative madness",[85] and a "mania".[86] Many observers have commented on this phenomenon[87][88][89]--as evidenced by the cover of the June 13, 2005 issue of Time Magazine[83] (itself taken as a sign of the bubble's peak[90])--but as a 2007 article in Forbes warns, "to realize that America's mania for home-buying is out of all proportion to sober reality, one needs to look no further than the current subprime lending mess... As interest rates--and mortgage payments--have started to climb, many of these new owners are having difficulty making ends meet... Those borrowers are much worse off than before they bought."[91] The boom in housing has also created a boom in the real estate profession; for example, California has a record half-million real estate licencees--one for every 52 adults living in the state, up 57% in the last five years.[92]

The overall U.S. homeownership rate increased from 64 percent in 1994 (about where it was since 1980) to a peak in 2004 with an all-time high of 69.2 percent.[93] Bush's 2004 campaign slogan "the ownership society" indicates the strong preference and societal influence of Americans to own the homes they live in, as opposed to renting. However, in many parts of the United States, rent does not cover mortgage costs; the national median mortgage payment is $1,687 per month, nearly twice the median rent payment of $868 per month, although this ratio can vary significantly from market to market.[94]

Suspicious Activity Reports pertaining to mortgage fraud increased by 1,411 percent between 1997 and 2005. Both borrowers seeking to obtain homes they could not otherwise afford, and industry insiders seeking monetary gain, were implicated.[95]

Belief that housing is a good investment[edit]

Among Americans, home ownership is widely accepted as preferable to renting in many cases, especially when the ownership term is expected to be at least five years. This is partly because the fraction of a fixed-rate mortgage used to pay down the principal builds equity for the homeowner over time, while the interest portion of the loan payments qualifies for a tax break, whereas, except for the personal tax deduction often available to renters but not to homeowners, money spent on rent does neither. However, when considered as an investment, that is, an asset that is expected to grow in value over time, as opposed to the utility of shelter that home ownership provides, housing is not a risk-free investment. The popular notion that, unlike stocks, homes do not fall in value is believed to have contributed to the mania for purchasing homes. Stock prices are reported in real time, which means investors witness the volatility. However, homes are usually valued yearly or less often, thereby smoothing out perceptions of volatility. This assertion that property prices rise has been true for the United States as a whole since the Great Depression,[96] and appears to be encouraged by the real estate industry.[97][98]

However, housing prices can move both up and down in local markets, as evidenced by the relatively recent price history in locations such as New YorkLos AngelesBostonJapanSeoulSydney, and Hong Kong; large trends of up and down price fluctuations can be seen in many U.S. cities (see graph). Since 2005, the year-over-year median sale prices (inflation-adjusted) of single family homes inMassachusetts fell over 10% in 2006.[citation needed] Economist David Lereah formerly of the National Association of Realtors (NAR) said in August 2006 that "he expects home prices to come down 5% nationally, more in some markets, less in others."[99] Commenting in August 2005 on the perceived low risk of housing as an investment vehicle, Alan Greenspan said, "history has not dealt kindly with the aftermath of protracted periods of low risk premiums."[100]

Compounding the popular expectation that home prices do not fall, it is also widely believed that home values will yield average or better-than-average returns as investments. The investment motive for purchasing homes should not be conflated with the necessity of shelter that housing provides; an economic comparison of the relative costs of owning versus renting the equivalent utility of shelter can be made separately (see boxed text). Over the holding periods of decades, inflation-adjusted house prices have increased less than 1% per year.[71][101]

Robert Shiller shows[71] that over long periods, inflation adjusted U.S. home prices increased 0.4% per year from 1890 to 2004, and 0.7% per year from 1940 to 2004. Piet Eichholtz also showed [102] in what has become known as the Herengracht house index, comparable results for housing prices on a single street in Amsterdam (the site of the fabled tulip mania, and where the housing supply is notably limited) over a 350 year period. Such meager returns are dwarfed by investments in the stock and bond markets; although, these investments are not heavily leveraged by fair interest loans. If historic trends hold, it is reasonable to expect home prices to only slightly beat inflation over the long term. Furthermore, one way to assess the quality of any investment is to compute its price-to-earnings (P/E) ratio, which for houses can be defined as the price of the house divided by the potential annual rental income, minus expenses including property taxes, maintenance, insurance, and condominium fees. For many locations, this computation yields a P/E ratio of about 30-40, which is considered by economists to be high for both the housing and the stock markets;[71] historical price-to-rent ratios are 11-12.[2] For comparison, just before the dot-com crash the P/E ratio of the S&P 500 was 45, while in 2005-2007 around 17.[103] In a 2007 article comparing the cost and risks of renting to buying using a buy vs. rent calculator, the New York Timesconcluded,

Homeownership, [realtors] argue, is a way to achieve the American dream, save on taxes and earn a solid investment return all at the same time. ... [I]t's now clear that people who chose renting over buying in the last two years made the right move. In much of the country ... recent home buyers have faced higher monthly costs than renters and have lost money on their investment in the meantime. It's almost as if they have thrown money away, an insult once reserved for renters.[104]

A 2007 Forbes article titled "Don't Buy That House" invokes similar arguments and concludes that for now, "resist the pressure [to buy]. There may be no place like home, but there's no reason you can't rent it."[91]

Promotion in the media[edit]

In late 2005 and into 2006, there were an abundance of television programs promoting real estate investment and flipping.[105][106] In addition to the numerous television shows, book stores in cities throughout the United States could be seen showing large displays of books touting real-estate investment, such as NAR chief economist David Lereah's book Are You Missing the Real Estate Boom?, subtitled Why Home Values and Other Real Estate Investments Will Climb Through The End of The Decade - And How to Profit From Them, published in February 2005.[107] One year later, Lereah retitled his book Why the Real Estate Boom Will Not Bust - And How You Can Profit from It.[108]

However, following Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke's comments on the "downturn of the housing market" in August 2006,[109]Lereah said in an NBC interview that "we've had a boom marketplace: you've got to correct because booms cannot sustain itself forever [sic]."[110] Commenting on the phenomenon of shifting NAR accounts of the national housing market (see David Lereah's comments[111][110][112]), the Motley Fool reported, "There's nothing funnier or more satisfying ... than watching the National Association of Realtors (NAR) change its tune these days. ... the NAR is full of it and will spin the numbers any way it can to keep up the pleasant fiction that all is well."[98]

Upon leaving the NAR in May 2007, Lereah explained to Robert Siegel of National Public Radio that using the word "boom" in the title was actually his publisher's idea, and "a poor choice of titles".[113]

Speculative fever[edit]

Total US derivatives and total US wealth 1995-2007 compared to total world wealth in the year 2000

The graph above shows the total notional value of derivatives relative to US Wealth measures. It is important to note for the casual observer that, in many cases, notional values of derivatives carry little meaning. Often the parties cannot easily agree on terms to close a derivative contract. The common solution has been to create an equal and opposite contract, often with a different party, in order to net payments (Derivatives market#Netting), thus eliminating all but the counterparty risk of the contract, but doubling the nominal value of outstanding contracts.

As median home prices began to rise dramatically in 2000-2001 following the fall in interest rates, speculative purchases of homes also increased.[114] Fortune magazine's article on housing speculation in 2005 said, "America was awash in a stark, raving frenzy that looked every bit as crazy as dot-com stocks."[115] In a 2006 interview in BusinessWeek magazine, Yale economist Robert Shiller said of the impact of speculators on long term valuations, "I worry about a big fall because prices today are being supported by a speculative fever",[116] and former NAR chief economist David Lereah said in 2005 that "[t]here's a speculative element in home buying now."[111][broken footnote] Speculation in some local markets has been greater than others, and any correction in valuations is expected to be strongly related to the percentage amount of speculative purchases.[112][117][118] In the same BusinessWeek interview, Angelo Mozilo, CEO of mortgage lender Countrywide Financial, said in March 2006:

In areas where you have had heavy speculation, you could have 30% [home price declines]... A year or a year and half from now, you will have seen a slow deterioration of home values and a substantial deterioration in those areas where there has been speculative excess.[116]

The chief economist for the National Association of Home Builders, David Seiders, said that California, Las Vegas, Florida and the Washington, D.C., area "have the largest potential for a price slowdown" because the rising prices in those markets were fed by speculators who bought homes intending to "flip" or sell them for a quick profit.[119] Dallas Fed president Richard Fisher said in 2006 that the Fed held its target rate at 1 percent "longer than it should have been" and unintentionally prompted speculation in the housing market.[69][70]

Various real estate investment advisors openly advocated the use of no money down property flipping, which led to the demise of many speculators who followed this strategy such as Casey Serin.[120][121]

Buying and selling above normal multiples[edit]

Home prices, as a multiple of annual rent, have been 15 since World War II. In the bubble, prices reached a multiple of 26. In 2008, prices had fallen to a multiple of 22.[122]

In some areas houses were selling at multiples of replacement costs, especially when prices were correctly adjusted for depreciation.[123][124] Cost per square foot indexes still show wide variability from city to city, therefore it may be that new houses can be built more cheaply in some areas than asking prices for existing homes.[125] [126] [127] [128]

Possible factors of this variation from city to city are housing supply constraints, both regulatory and geographical. Regulatory constraints such as urban growth boundaries serve to reduce the amount of developable land and thus increase prices for new housing construction. Geographic constraints (water bodies, wetlands, and slopes) cannot be ignored either. It is debatable which type of constraint contributes more to price fluctuations. Some argue that the latter, by inherently increasing the value of land in a defined area (because the amount of usable land is less), give homeowners and developers incentive to support regulations to further protect the value of their property.[129]

In this case, geographical constraints beget regulatory action. To the contrary, others will argue that geographic constraints are only a secondary factor, pointing to the more discernable effects that urban growth boundaries have on housing prices in such places as Portland, OR.[130] Despite the presence of geographic constraints in the surrounding Portland area, their current urban growth boundary does not encompass those areas. Therefore, one would argue, such geographic constraints are a non issue.

Dot-com bubble collapse[edit]

Yale economist Robert Shiller argues that the 2000 stock market crash displaced "irrational exuberance" from the fallen stock market to residential real estate: "Once stocks fell, real estate became the primary outlet for the speculative frenzy that the stock market had unleashed."[131]

The crash of the dot-com and technology sectors in 2000 led to a (approximately) 70% drop in the NASDAQ composite index. Shiller and several other economists have argued this resulted in many people taking their money out of the stock market and purchasing real estate, believing it to be a more reliable investment.[68][101][132]

Risky mortgage products and lax lending standards[edit]

Common indexes used for Adjustable Rate Mortgages (1996-2006).

Excessive consumer housing debt was in turn caused by the mortgage-backed security,credit default swap, and collateralized debt obligation sub-sectors of the finance industry, which were offering irrationally low interest rates and irrationally high levels of approval tosubprime mortgage consumers because they were calculating aggregate risk usinggaussian copula formulas that strictly assumed the independence of individual component mortgages, when in fact the credit-worthiness almost every new subprime mortgage was highly correlated with that of any other because of linkages through consumer spending levels which fell sharply when property values began to fall during the initial wave of mortgage defaults.[133][134] Debt consumers were acting in their rational self-interest, because they were unable to audit the finance industry's opaque faulty risk pricing methodology.[135]

Expansion of subprime lending[edit]

Low interest rates, high home prices, and flipping (or reselling homes to make a profit), effectively created an almost risk-free environment for lenders because risky or defaulted loans could be paid back by flipping homes.

Private lenders pushed subprime mortgages to capitalize on this, aided by greater market power for mortgage originators and less market power for mortgage securitizers.[18] Subprime mortgages amounted to $35 billion (5% of total originations) in 1994,[136] 9% in 1996,[137] $160 billion (13%) in 1999,[136] and $600 billion (20%) in 2006.[137][138][139]

Risky products[edit]

The recent use of subprime mortgagesadjustable rate mortgagesinterest-only mortgages, and stated income loans (a subset of "Alt-A" loans, where the borrower did not have to provide documentation to substantiate the income stated on the application; these loans were also called "no doc" (no documentation) loans and, somewhat pejoratively, as "liar loans") to finance home purchases described above have raised concerns about the quality of these loans should interest rates rise again or the borrower is unable to pay the mortgage.[71][140][141][142]

In many areas, particularly in those with most appreciation, non-standard loans went from almost unheard of to prevalent. For example, 80% of all mortgages initiated in San Diego region in 2004 were adjustable-rate, and 47% were interest only.

In 1995, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac began receiving affordable housing credit for buying Alt-A securities [143] Academic opinion is divided on how much this contributed to GSE purchases of nonprime MBS and to growth of nonprime mortgage origination.[18]

Some borrowers got around downpayment requirements by using seller-funded downpayment assistance programs (DPA), in which a seller gives money to a charitable organizations that then give the money to them. From 2000 through 2006, more than 650,000 buyers got their down payments through nonprofits.[144] According to a Government Accountability Office study, there are higher default and foreclosure rates for these mortgages. The study also showed that sellers inflated home prices to recoup their contributions to the nonprofits.[145]

On May 4, 2006, the IRS ruled that such plans are no longer eligible for non-profit status due to the circular nature of the cash flow, in which the seller pays the charity a "fee" after closing.[146] On October 31, 2007, the Department of Housing and Urban Development adopted new regulations banning so-called "seller-funded" downpayment programs. Most must cease providing grants on FHA loans immediately; one can operate until March 31, 2008.[144]

Mortgage standards became lax because of a moral hazard, where each link in the mortgage chain collected profits while believing it was passing on risk.[18][147] Mortgage denial rates for conventional home purchase loans, reported under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act, have dropped noticeably, from 29 percent in 1998, to 14 percent in 2002 and 2003.[148] Traditional gatekeepers such as mortgage securitizers and credit rating agencies lost their ability to maintain high standards because of competitive pressures.[18]

Mortgage risks were underestimated by every institution in the chain from originator to investor by underweighting the possibility of falling housing prices given historical trends of rising prices.[149][150] These authors argue that misplaced confidence in innovation and excessive optimism led to miscalculations by both public and private institutions.

In March 2007, the United States' subprime mortgage industry collapsed due to higher-than-expected home foreclosure rates, with more than 25 subprime lenders declaring bankruptcy, announcing significant losses, or putting themselves up for sale.[151] Harper's Magazine warned of the danger of rising interest rates for recent homebuyers holding such mortgages, as well as the U.S. economy as a whole: "The problem [is] that prices are falling even as the buyers' total mortgage remains the same or even increases. ... Rising debt-service payments will further divert income from new consumer spending. Taken together, these factors will further shrink the "real” economy, drive down those already declining real wages, and push our debt-ridden economy into Japan-style stagnation or worse."[152]

Factors that could contribute to rising rates are the U.S. national debt, inflationary pressure caused by such factors as increased fuel and housing costs, and changes in foreign investments in the U.S. economy. The Fed raised rates 17 times, increasing them from 1% to 5.25%, between 2004 and 2006.[73] BusinessWeek magazine called the option ARM "the riskiest and most complicated home loan product ever created" and warned that over one million borrowers took out $466 billion in option ARMs in 2004 through the second quarter of 2006, citing concerns that these financial products could hurt individual borrowers the most and "worsen the [housing] bust."[153]

To address the problems arising from "liar loans", the Internal Revenue Service updated an income verification tool used by lenders to make confirmation of borrower's claimed income to be faster and easier.[141] In April 2007, financial problems similar to the subprime mortgages began to appear with Alt-A loans made to homeowners who were thought to be less risky; the delinquency rate for Alt-A mortgages rose in 2007.[154] The manager of the world's largest bond fund PIMCO, warned in June 2007 that the subprime mortgage crisis was not an isolated event and will eventually take a toll on the economy and whose ultimate impact will be on the impaired prices of homes.[155]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. Jump up^ A derivation for the monthly cost is provided at usenet's sci.math FAQ.
  2. Jump up to:a b Tully, Shawn (2003-12-22). "The New Home Economics".Fortune.
  3. Jump up to:a b "Who Caused the Economic Crisis?". FactCheck.org. Retrieved 2010-01-21.
  4. Jump up to:a b Did Fannie and Freddie Cause the Housing Bubble? Daniel Indiviglio June 3, 2010
  5. Jump up^ A Summary of the Primary Causes of the Housing Bubble and the Resulting Credit Crisis: A Non-Technical Paper By JEFF HOLT
  6. Jump up^ McLean, Bethany (2010, 2011). All the Devils Are Here. NY: Portfolio/Penguin. p. 365. Check date values in: |date= (help)
  7. Jump up to:a b 1. Proposal for Amending I.R.C. §121 and §1034 U.S. House of Representatives
  8. Jump up^ Impact of 1986 Tax Reform Act on Homeowners TodayHomeFinder.com, August 5, 2008
  9. Jump up^ 1. Proposal for Amending I.R.C. §121 and §1034 'U.S. House of Representatives
  10. Jump up^ The Clinton Housing BubbleVernon L. SmithThe Wall Street Journal, December 18, 2007
  11. Jump up^ Tax Break May Have Helped Cause Housing Bubble, Vikas Bajaj and David Leonhardt, The New York Times, December 18, 2008
  12. Jump up^ http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123897612802791281.htmlFrom Bubble to Depression?], Steven Gjerstad and Vernon L. Smith, Wall Street Journal, April 6, 2009
  13. Jump up^ Madrick, Jeff (2011-12-09). "What Bill Clinton Would Do"New York Times. Retrieved 2012-01-27.
  14. Jump up^ The Gramm connectionPaul KrugmanThe New York Times. Published March 29, 2008.
  15. Jump up^ Who's Whining Now? Gramm Slammed By EconomistsABC News. Sept. 19, 2008.
  16. Jump up^ John McCain: Crisis EnablerThe Nation. September 21, 2008.
  17. Jump up^ Ekelund, Robert; Thornton, Mark (2008-09-04). "More Awful Truths About Republicans"Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved 2008-09-07.
  18. Jump up to:a b c d e f g Michael Simkovic, Competition and Crisis in Mortgage Securitization
  19. Jump up^ Joseph Fried, Who Really Drove the Economy Into the Ditch(New York: Algora Publishing, 2012) 289-90.
  20. Jump up to:a b c d Konczal, Mike (13 February 2013). "No, Marco Rubio, government did not cause the housing crisis"Washington Post. Retrieved 13 February 2013.
  21. Jump up^ full text of Sen. Marco Rubio's (R-FL) Republican Address to the Nation, as prepared for delivery
  22. Jump up to:a b Peter J. Wallison, "Dissent from the Majority Report of the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission,” (Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, January 2011), 61, www.aei.org.
  23. Jump up^ Joseph Fried, Who Really Drove the Economy Into the Ditch? (New York, NY: Algora Publishing, 2012), 121.
  24. Jump up^ Joseph Fried, Who Really Drove the Economy Into the Ditch? (New York, NY: Algora Publishing, 2012), Chapter 6.
  25. Jump up^ Stan Liebowtiz, The Real Scandal - How feds invited the mortgage messNew York Post, February 5, 2008
  26. Jump up^ Edward Pinto, "Yes, the CRA is Toxic," City Journal, 2009
  27. Jump up^ Gillespie, Mark (2009-12-13). "How Cleveland Aggravated Its Foreclosure Problem and Lost Millions in Tax Dollars - All to Help People Purchase Homes They Couldn't Afford"Cleveland Plain Dealer. Cleveland.com. Retrieved 2013-12-10.
  28. Jump up^ Russell Roberts"How Government Stoked the Mania"Wall Street Journal, October 3, 2008.
  29. Jump up to:a b c d "Private sector loans, not Fannie or Freddie, triggered crisis"McClatchy. 12/3/2008. Check date values in: |date=(help)
  30. Jump up to:a b Min, David. "Why Wallison Is Wrong About the Genesis of the U.S. Housing Crisis"Center for American Progress, July 12, 2011. americanprogress.org. Retrieved 13 February 2013.
  31. Jump up^ Peter J. Wallison (January 2011). "Dissent from the Majority Report of the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission". American Enterprise Institute. Retrieved 2012-11-20.
  32. Jump up^ Sanders, Anthony B. and An, Xudong, Default of CMBS Loans During the Crisis (November 29, 2010). 46th Annual AREUEA Conference Paper. Available at SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1717062
  33. Jump up^ Amadeo, Kimberly, "Commercial Real Estate Lending" in News & Issues-US Economy(About.com, November, 2013),http://useconomy.about.com/od/grossdomesticproduct/tp/Commercial-Real-Estate-Loan-Defaults.htm
  34. Jump up^ Gierach, Denice A., "Waiting for the other shoe to drop in commercial real estate," (Chicago, IL, The Business Ledger, March 4, 2010)
  35. Jump up^ Mclean, Bethany (2010, 2011). All the Devils Are Here. New York: Porfolio/Penguin. p. 363. ISBN 9781591843634. Check date values in: |date= (help)
  36. Jump up to:a b Joseph Fried, Who Really Drove the Economy Into the Ditch? (New York, NY: Algora Publishing, 2012), 141.
  37. Jump up^ "FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC Analysis of Options for Revising the Housing Enterprises' Long-term Structures" (PDF).September 2009. United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Committees. Retrieved 14 February 2013.
  38. Jump up^ "Harvard Report Finds Excessive Risk Taking and Lapses in Regulation Led to the Nonprime Mortgage Lending Boom".September 27, 2010. Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University. Retrieved 14 Feb 2013.
  39. Jump up^ "CONCLUSIONS OF THE FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION" (PDF). FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION. Retrieved 14 Feb 2013.
  40. Jump up^ "Data on the Risk Characteristics and Performance of Single-Family Mortgages Originated from 2001 through 2008 and Financed in the Secondary Market" (PDF)September 13, 2010. Federal Housing Finance Agency. Retrieved 14 Feb 2013.
  41. Jump up^ Park, Kevin. "Fannie, Freddie and the Foreclosure Crisis".Kevin Park,. UNC Center for Community Capital. Retrieved14 February 2013.
  42. Jump up^ Glaeser, Edward L.; Joseph Gyourko; Albert Saiz (June 2008)."Housing supply and housing bubbles."Journal of Urban Economics64 (2): 198-217. doi:10.1016/j.jue.2008.07.007. Retrieved 14 February 2013.
  43. Jump up^ Thomas, Jason. "Housing Policy, Subprime Markets and Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac: What We Know, What We Think We Know and What We Don't Know" (PDF)November 2010. stlouisfed.org. Retrieved 14 Feb 2013.
  44. Jump up^ SEC Charges Former Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Executives with Securities Fraud," Securities and Exchange Commission, December 16, 2011, http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2011/2011-267.htm.
  45. Jump up^ WALLISON, PETER. "The Financial Crisis on Trial"December 21, 2011. wsj.com. Retrieved 21 June 2013.
  46. Jump up^ Peter J. Wallison and Edward Pinto, "Why the Left is Losing the Argument over the Financial Crisis," (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, December 27, 2011)
  47. Jump up^ Kroszner, Randall S. "The Community Reinvestment Act and the Recent Mortgage Crisis"Speech at the Confronting Concentrated Poverty Policy Forum. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D.C.December 3, 2008. Retrieved 13 February 2013.
  48. Jump up^ "Fed's Kroszner: Don't Blame CRA"Wall Street Journal. 12/3/2008. Check date values in: |date= (help)
  49. Jump up^ Sheila Bair; FDIC Chairman (2008-12-17). "Prepared Remarks:Did Low-income Homeownership Go Too Far?"Conference before the New America Foundation. FDIC.
  50. Jump up^ Seidman, Ellen. "Don't Blame the Community Reinvestment Act"The American Prospect. www.prospect.org. Retrieved2009-08-12.
  51. Jump up^ Regulation and the Mortgage Crisis, 2011
  52. Jump up^ NBER-Agarwal, Benmelich, Bergman, Seru-"Did the Community Reinvestment Act Lead to Risky Lending?"
  53. Jump up^ Far Too Low for Far Too Long| JW Mason| April 6, 2012
  54. Jump up^ Conventional Fed Wisdom, Defied| By GRETCHEN MORGENSON| 13 August 2011
  55. Jump up^ Greenspan, Alan (2007-09-16). "A global outlook"Financial Times.
  56. Jump up^ Congressman Barney Frank Hearing Before the Committee on Financial Services: US House of Representatives, 108th Congress, first session,9-10-2003 pg 3
  57. Jump up^ Hearing Before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs: US Senate, 108th Congress, first and second session,2-25-2004 pg 454
  58. Jump up^ "A (Sub)Prime Argument for More Regulation" Financial Times of London, pg 11 8-20-2007 quotes Congressman Barney Frank
  59. Jump up^ Senator Dodd
  60. Jump up^ Greenspan, Alan (2005-12-06). "Housing Bubble Bursts in the Market for U.S. Mortgage Bonds"BloombergFroth in housing markets may be spilling over into mortgage markets.
  61. Jump up^ "International Finance Discussion Papers, Number 841, House Prices and Monetary Policy: A Cross-Country Study" (PDF).Federal Reserve Board. September 2005. Like other asset prices, house prices are influenced by interest rates, and in some countries, the housing market is a key channel of monetary policy transmission.
  62. Jump up^ Roach, Stephen (2004-02-26). "The American economy: A phoney recovery, Drug addicts get only a temporary high. America's economy, addicted to asset appreciation and debt, is no different"The EconomistThe Fed, in effect, has become a serial bubble blower.
  63. Jump up^ Wallace-Wells, Benjamin (April 2004). "There Goes the Neighborhood: Why home prices are about to plummet--and take the recovery with them."Washington Monthly.
  64. Jump up^ Roach, Stephen (2005). "Morgan Stanley Global Economic Forum: Original Sin"Morgan Stanley. See also James Wolcott'scomments.
  65. Jump up^ Phillips, Kevin (2006). American Theocracy: The Peril and Politics of Radical Religion, Oil, and Borrowed Money in the 21st Century. Viking. ISBN 0-670-03486-X.
  66. Jump up^ Krugman, Paul (2006-08-07). "Intimations of a Recession"The New York Times.
  67. Jump up^ Fleckenstein, Bill (2006-08-21). "Face it: The housing bust is here"MSN.
  68. Jump up to:a b "Is A Housing Bubble About To Burst?"BusinessWeek. 2004-07-19. Retrieved 2008-03-17.
  69. Jump up to:a b "Official Says Bad Data Fueled Rate Cuts, Housing Speculation"The Wall Street Journal. 2006-11-06. In retrospect, the real Fed funds rate turned out to be lower than what was deemed appropriate at the time and was held lower longer than it should have been... In this case, poor data led to a policy action that amplified speculative activity in the housing and other markets... Toda... the housing market is undergoing a substantial correction and inflicting real costs to millions of homeowners across the country. It is complicating the [Fed's] task of achieving... sustainable noninflationary growth.
  70. Jump up to:a b "Fed's Bies, Fisher See Inflation Rate Beginning to Come Down"Bloomberg. 2006-11-03.
  71. Jump up to:a b c d e f Shiller, Robert (2005). Irrational Exuberance (2d ed.).Princeton University PressISBN 0-691-12335-7.
  72. Jump up^ Thomas Sowell (2010). The Housing Boom and Bust: Revised Edition. Basic Books. pp. 1-29. ISBN 978-0465019861.
  73. Jump up to:a b "Fed holds rates for first time in two years"Financial Times. 2006-08-08.
  74. Jump up^ Roubini, Nouriel (2006-08-09). "Fed Holds Interest Rates Steady As Slowdown Outweighs Inflation"The Wall Street JournalThe Fed should have tightened earlier to avoid a festering of the housing bubble early on. The Fed is facing a nightmare now: the recession will come and easing will not prevent it.
  75. Jump up^ Reese, Chris (2007-06-14). "Poll: Fed to leave U.S. rates at 5.25 percent through end-2008"Reuters.
  76. Jump up^ "In bold stroke, Fed cuts base rate half point to 4.75 percent".AFP. 2007-09-17.
  77. Jump up^ "Greenspan: 'Local bubbles' build in housing sector"USA Today. 2005-05-20.
  78. Jump up^ "Greenspan alert on US house prices"Financial Times. 2007-09-17.
  79. Jump up^ "S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price Indices-historical spreadsheets".
  80. Jump up^ Christie, Les (2007-08-14). "California cities fill top 10 foreclosure list"CNNMoney.com. Retrieved 2010-05-26.
  81. Jump up^ "Home prices tumble as consumer confidence sinks"Reuters. 2007-11-27. Retrieved 2008-03-17.
  82. Jump up^ Knox, Noelle (2006-11-21). "Cleveland: Foreclosures weigh on market"USA Today.
  83. Jump up to:a b "Home $weet Home"Time. 2005-06-13.
  84. Jump up^ Greenspan, Alan (2005-05-20). "Greenspan Calls Home-Price Speculation Unsustainable"BloombergAt a minimum, there's a little froth [in the U.S. housing market]... It's hard not to see that there are a lot of local bubbles.
  85. Jump up^ Evans-Pritchard, Ambrose (2006-03-23). "No mercy now, no bail-out later"The Daily Telegraph. London. Retrieved 2010-04-28[T]he American housing boom is now the mother of all bubbles--in sheer volume, if not in degrees of speculative madness.
  86. Jump up^ "Episode 06292007". Bill Moyers Journalhttp://www.pbs.org/moyers/journal/06292007/transcript5.html |transcripturl= missing title (help). 2007-06-29. PBS.
Last modified: Tuesday, August 14, 2018, 9:41 AM